House Monotonicity
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

House monotonicity (also called house-size monotonicity) is a property of
apportionment methods The legal term apportionment (french: apportionement; Mediaeval Latin: , derived from la, portio, share), also called delimitation, is in general the distribution or allotment of proper shares, though may have different meanings in different c ...
and
multiwinner voting Multiwinner voting, also called multiple-winner elections or committee voting or committee elections, is an electoral system in which multiple candidates are elected. The number of elected candidates is usually fixed in advance. For example, it can ...
systems. These are methods for allocating seats in a
parliament In modern politics, and history, a parliament is a legislative body of government. Generally, a modern parliament has three functions: Representation (politics), representing the Election#Suffrage, electorate, making laws, and overseeing ...
among
federal states A federation (also known as a federal state) is a political entity characterized by a union of partially self-governing provinces, states, or other regions under a central federal government (federalism). In a federation, the self-governi ...
(or among
political party A political party is an organization that coordinates candidates to compete in a particular country's elections. It is common for the members of a party to hold similar ideas about politics, and parties may promote specific political ideology ...
). The property says that, if the number of seats in the "house" (the parliament) increases, and the method is re-activated, then no state should have less seats than it previously had. A method that fails to satisfy house-monotonicity is said to have the Alabama paradox. House monotonicity is the special case of ''
resource monotonicity Resource monotonicity (RM; aka aggregate monotonicity) is a principle of fair division. It says that, if there are more resources to share, then all agents should be weakly better off; no agent should lose from the increase in resources. The RM pri ...
'' for the setting in which the resource consists of identical discrete items (the seats).


Methods violating house-monotonicity

An example of a method violating house-monotonicity is the
largest remainder method The largest remainder method (also known as Hare–Niemeyer method, Hamilton method or as Vinton's method) is one way of allocating seats proportionally for representative assemblies with party list voting systems. It contrasts with various h ...
(= Hamilton's method). Consider the following instance with three states: When one seat is added to the house, the share of state C decreases from 2 to 1. This occurs because increasing the number of seats increases the fair share faster for the large states than for the small states. In particular, large A and B had their fair share increase faster than small C. Therefore, the fractional parts for A and B increased faster than those for C. In fact, they overtook C's fraction, causing C to lose its seat, since the method examines which states have the largest remaining fraction. This violation is known as the Alabama paradox due to the history of its discovery. After the 1880 census, C. W. Seaton, chief clerk of the
United States Census Bureau The United States Census Bureau (USCB), officially the Bureau of the Census, is a principal agency of the U.S. Federal Statistical System, responsible for producing data about the American people and economy. The Census Bureau is part of the ...
, computed apportionments for all House sizes between 275 and 350, and discovered that
Alabama (We dare defend our rights) , anthem = "Alabama (state song), Alabama" , image_map = Alabama in United States.svg , seat = Montgomery, Alabama, Montgomery , LargestCity = Huntsville, Alabama, Huntsville , LargestCounty = Baldwin County, Al ...
would get eight seats with a House size of 299 but only seven with a House size of 300. Simulation experiments show that monotonicity violations can be quite common. For example, in random elections, Hamilton's method has a chance of 1/18 to violate monotonicity.


Methods satisfying house-monotonicity


Methods for apportionment

All the highest-averages methods (= divisor methods) satisfy house monotonicity. This is easy to see when considering the implementation of divisor methods as picking sequences: when a seat are added, the only change is that the picking sequence is extended with one additional pick. Therefore, all states keep their previously-picked seats. Similarly, rank-index methods, which are generalizations of divisor methods, satisfy house-monotonicity. Moreover, ''capped divisor methods'', which are variants of divisor methods in which a state never gets more seats than its upper quota, also satisfy house-monotonicity. An example is the Balinsky-
Young Young may refer to: * Offspring, the product of reproduction of a new organism produced by one or more parents * Youth, the time of life when one is young, often meaning the time between childhood and adulthood Music * The Young, an American roc ...
quota method. Every house-monotone method can be defined as a recursive function of the house size ''h''.'''' Formally, an apportionment method M(\mathbf,h) is house-monotone and satisfies both quotas if-and-only-if it is constructed recursively as follows (see
mathematics of apportionment Mathematics of apportionment describes mathematical principles and algorithms for fair allocation of identical items among parties with different entitlements. Such principles are used to apportion seats in parliaments among federal states or polit ...
for the definitions and notation): * M(\mathbf,0) = 0; * If M(\mathbf,h) = \mathbf, then M(\mathbf,h+1) is found by giving a_i+1 seats to some single state i\in U(\mathbf,\mathbf)\cap L(\mathbf,\mathbf), where: **U(\mathbf,\mathbf) is the set of states that can get an additional seat without violating their upper quota for the new house size; **L(\mathbf,\mathbf) is the set of states that might receive less than their lower quota for some future house size. Every
coherent Coherence, coherency, or coherent may refer to the following: Physics * Coherence (physics), an ideal property of waves that enables stationary (i.e. temporally and spatially constant) interference * Coherence (units of measurement), a deri ...
apportionment method is house-monotone.


Methods for multiwinner voting

Phragmen's voting rules Phragmén's voting rules are multiwinner voting methods that guarantee proportional representation. They were published by Lars Edvard Phragmén in French and Swedish between 1893 and 1899, and translated to English by Svante Janson in 2016. Ther ...
, both for approval ballots and for ranked ballots, are house-monotone. The same is true for Thiele's addition method and Thiele's elimination method. However, Thiele's optimization method is not house-monotone.{{Rp, Sec.5


See also

*
Resource monotonicity Resource monotonicity (RM; aka aggregate monotonicity) is a principle of fair division. It says that, if there are more resources to share, then all agents should be weakly better off; no agent should lose from the increase in resources. The RM pri ...
- a generalization of house-monotonicity to possibly different items. *
Monotonicity criterion The monotonicity criterion is a voting system criterion used to evaluate both single and multiple winner ranked voting systems. A ranked voting system is monotonic if it is neither possible to prevent the election of a candidate by ranking them h ...
- a different criterion, used for ranked voting systems.


References

Apportionment method criteria Electoral system criteria